[Book Review] Fahad Ahmad Bishara, A Sea of Debt – Law and Economic Life in the Western Indian Ocean, 1780-1950 & Johan Mathew, Margins of the Market: Trafficking and Capitalism Across the Arabian Sea

Sebastian W. Bernburg presented an earlier version of this review essay at the 2017 Book Review Colloquium on Islamic and Middle East Studies organized by Ali Vural Ak Center for Global Islamic Studies at George Mason University.
[Book Review] Fahad Ahmad Bishara, A Sea of Debt – Law and Economic Life in the Western Indian Ocean, 1780-1950 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2017). 288 pages; ISBN:9781107155657 & Johan Mathew, Margins of the Market: Trafficking and Capitalism Across the Arabian Sea (Oakland: University of California Press, 2016) 272 pages; ISBN:9780520288553. Reviewed by Sebastian W. Bernburg

Islamic law and commerce have been interlinked since the early days of Islam. In recent years, one book in particular, The Long Divergence – How Islam Held Back the Middle East (2011) by Timur Kuran has attracted a lot of attention for its discussion of Islam’s role in the relative decline of the Muslim world’s ability to compete internationally during the nineteenth century. In Kuran’s narrative, sophisticated modes of commerce from the early Islamic period became outdated and repressive when European polities increasingly secularized their trading practices. While Kuran’s narrative is compelling, two recently published books contest this generalizing and theoretical account of the relationship between Islamic law and commerce. Johan Mathew’s Margins of the Market – Trafficking and Capitalism Across the Arabian Sea (2016) and Fahad Ahmad Bishara’s A Sea of Debt – Law and Economic Life in the Western Indian Ocean 1780-1950 (2017) provide two new approaches to this topic. “

Both books examine what would be considered by many in the field of Middle East Studies and beyond to be the periphery of the Islamic world, the Western Indian Ocean during the nineteenth century. This region was particular in that it was a space embedded in technological and judicial contrasts, ethnic diversity, and a contest for sovereignty.”
Both books examine what would be considered by many in the field of Middle East Studies and beyond to be the periphery of the Islamic world, the Western Indian Ocean during the nineteenth century. This region was particular in that it was a space embedded in technological and judicial contrasts, ethnic diversity, and a contest for sovereignty. In this space, Islamic law, and its relation to commerce, was neither static nor uniform – it was continuously reinterpreted and highly diverse.

Islamic Law in the Western Indian Ocean

Johan Mathew describes his goal as one that “seeks to make virtue out of a failing: it attempts to trace the tactic of sailors and traders by paying close attention to the silences in different forms of documentation and triangulating between them.” (Mathew, 18) From these silences, in primarily British archival documents, he portrays how Indian, African, and Arab traders responded to the legal transformation of the Indian Ocean throughout the nineteenth century. In contrast, the bulk of Fahad Bishara’s data is excavated from the Zanzibar archives from two fatwa collections by the Ibadi legal scholars. At the center of Bishara’s narrative are deeds of debt, waraqas, which he uses to show the way debt structured trade in the region during the nineteenth century and how this structure changed over time as British interventions became more invasive. Bishara uses the waraqa and the fatwa collections to reconstruct “the context, actors, writings and exchanges – both actual and discursive – that constituted” (Bishara, 252)

“At the center of Bishara’s narrative are deeds of debt, waraqas, which he uses to show the way debt structured trade in the region during the nineteenth century and how this structure changed over time as British interventions became more invasive.”
Islamic law in the time and space he is studying, instead of viewing Islamic financial mechanisms and institutions as a product of centuries-old monolithic laws, like so many others have done before him. The two books complement each other well precisely because of the authors’ different methodologies, foci and the type of documents they use.

Framing Out

Johan Mathew’s primary focus in Margins of the Market is the intersection between how Europeans sought to redefine licit and illicit commercial practices in the Western Indian Ocean and the way in which those merchants, who suddenly found themselves on the ‘margins of the market,’ responded to these changes in order to maintain their trade operations. What also emerges, however, is the notion of Islamic law being utilized as a medium to evade European imperial impositions. The first real attempt to undercut Omani sovereignty by European bureaucrats was the signing of the 1822 treaty between the Sultan of Muscat and Zanzibar and the British Empire, which abolished slavery.

“Johan Mathew’s primary focus in Margins of the Market is the intersection between how Europeans sought to redefine licit and illicit commercial practices in the Western Indian Ocean and the way in which those merchants, who suddenly found themselves on the ‘margins of the market,’ responded to these changes in order to maintain their trade operations.”
 This was the first example of what Mathew calls framing out. Central to his argument is the notion that European bureaucrats, as their presence in the region intensified, sought to frame out certain elements of economic life in an effort to create a homogeneous order of exchange.

The framing out of slavery, violence, and counterfeits prompted responses by the Indian and Arab merchants, who were now on the margins of the market, and who instead had to utilize family ties, personal networks, and Islamic law to circumvent these new British rules. Slavery as a practice did not cease to exist because of the 1822 treaty, but slavers found new ways of transporting their slaves by reframing them as domestic slaveholding rather than available at the market place. “Slave traders discovered that the best way to avoid detection was not to be invisible but rather to make slaves perfectly visible to British authorities as servants.” (Mathew, 68). In essence, slavers reframed their activities as Islamic to the British authorities, allowing them to circumvent the new regulations. Besides seeking to frame out commodities and modes of transportation such as the dhow, the European officials wanted to reinvent modes of exchange in the region.

Europeans vs. The Native Institutions

As European intervention continued to intensify, the different imaginaries of market and money between natives to the region and Europeans became more pronounced. European regulators strove to commoditize money making it easier to measure value across different regions. In contrast, Islamic institutions such as the muhtasib, the market inspector, were already in place regulating markets and upholding the morals of exchange. The muhtasib governing of the market exchanges was embedded not only in the prevention of hisba, preventing evil and encouraging good as prescribed in Islamic law, but also through the prohibition of unequal exchanges such as those stipulated in the famous hadith gold for gold/ silver for silver. Therefore, coins found around the Western Indian Ocean were evaluated by their metallic content and not by the imagined value of the coin itself.

Critique

Mathew’s method of shedding light on the silent elements of the market by utilizing mostly British archival documents is largely successful. Particularly in the first three chapters, however, he appears to be over-amplifying the significance of the silences in the sources that he seeks to give a voice. Surely, the irritation and constant renewal of regulations does display practices on the margins of the market. However, to what degree? We cannot know the scope of these illicit activities, particularly when the sources he uses predominantly speak to only a few cases each. We also do not know the extent to which the regulations introduced by the British, and at times the European community, was a result of speculation or a few number of cases that proved illicit trafficking, or if their regulations were due to the large scope of illicit activity that Mathew is suggesting.  In any case, the examples that Mathew employs, in his well-written narrative, does show us that with structure, agency follows. Perhaps even more importantly, Mathew reminds us that the roots of capitalism were not based on an ideal of free markets, but formed by extensive regulations that dictated what was to be framed as licit and illicit in the market.

“Perhaps even more importantly, Mathew reminds us that the roots of capitalism were not based on an ideal of free markets, but formed by extensive regulations that dictated what was to be framed as licit and illicit in the market.”

A Sea of Debt

Fahad Bishara’s A Sea of Debt seeks to reconstruct the changing political, social and financial environments of the Western Indian Ocean through the medium of waraqas, deeds of debt, which Bishara persuasively argues regulated cross-cultural exchanges and relationships between Arab, Indian, African, and British actors. Similar to the trajectory seen in Margins of the Market, Islamic financial institutions eventually became redefined and were phased out by the intensification of British bureaucracy during the late nineteenth century and into the early twentieth century. Debt is permitted according to Islamic law, however interest-bearing loans are generally perceived as prohibited. The partnership contracts, mudaraba, had been utilized since the early days of the Islamic era for generating capital for business ventures in a world where interest was prohibited. Another system of generating capital and allowing for social mobility developed gradually in the form of different kinds of ‘pawnship loans’. The preferred pawnship loan in Oman and Zanzibar in the early nineteenth century was the khiyar sale, which was tied to the loaner’s property. Bishara defines the khiyar sale as “an exchange of capital (i.e. a loan) for rents (i.e. harvest or monetary payments) for a finite period of time, after which the debtor could redeem the property or transfer it to his creditor.” (Bishara, 92).

“Fahad Bishara’s A Sea of Debt seeks to reconstruct the changing political, social and financial environments of the Western Indian Ocean through the medium of waraqas, deeds of debt, which Bishara persuasively argues regulated cross-cultural exchanges and relationships between Arab, Indian, African, and British actors.”
Because the waraqa was such a prominent facet of exchanges in the nineteenth century, Bishara concurs that the non-Muslim or non-Arabs were drawn into “a distinct Arabian social imaginary,” Which included not only individuals, but also corporations. Bishara’s observation regarding the ascription of legal personhood to corporations is another facet of the book, which illuminates the flexibility of the Muslim jurists. A conventional critique, by those claiming that Islamic law held back the Middle East, is that Islamic lawmakers failed to incorporate the notion of corporations. However, as shown by Bishara that was not the case in the Omani Sultanate.

The Waraqa

During the 1870s and 1880s the space of the Western Indian Ocean changed dramatically. The British protectorates in East Africa that were established in the 1890s transformed the nature of the waraqa. The waraqa was now being officially registered in all parts of the Indian Ocean and administered by the British in parts of it. Like the Arabian understanding of ‘tribe’ and ‘clan’ had included the Indian and African merchants into the realm of the Arabian social world, the British now sought to transform notions like khiyar to the British legal framework, making it more of a “Muslim mortgage.” By the 1920s and 1930s waraqa was “no longer an instrument that coordinated between commercial and legal actors alone; it had become an instrument by which the government bureaucracy could actively intervene in everyday transactions.” (Bishara, 240)

“It is exactly the focus on transformation of the legal loan practices that makes A Sea of Debt such a valuable contribution to the field of the legal history of Islam. By focusing on the legal framework of one polity, the Omani Sultanate, in a limited time-frame, Bishara is able to contest narratives that articulate practices embedded in Islamic jurisprudence as static.”

Interestingly, it was not only the Europeans that transformed the khiyar. It was transformed over time as merchants asked Islamic legal scholars, like Khalili, about what criteria made transactions permissible. It is exactly the focus on transformation of the legal loan practices that makes A Sea of Debt such a valuable contribution to the field of the legal history of Islam. By focusing on the legal framework of one polity, the Omani Sultanate, in a limited time-frame, Bishara is able to contest narratives that articulate practices embedded in Islamic jurisprudence as static.

Contextual, Region Specific Perspective

Bishara, with A Sea of Debt, writes himself into the discussions that arose particularly after the publication of Timur Kuran’s The Long Divergence, by providing a new approach to the field. Rather than proposing a grand narrative of how Islamic scholars in the first 300 years of hijra formed the trajectory of Islamic finance that eventually led to an unequal power balance between the East and West, he proposes a more region- specific and context-based approach that shows that market fluctuations and local- and geo-politics shaped the reality of state and individual actors. A Sea of Debt is an important contribution to the field as it proposes a new and beneficial approach to the study of the history of Islamic law, which is wrapped in a page turning narrative that de-essentializes the framing of Islamic law by looking at a specific time and space.

While A Sea of Debt and Margins of the Market are undoubtedly top-notch research manuscripts, one aspect of both books that is vulnerable to critique is the general lack of explicit reflection in regards to their usage of primary source material. Mathew’s reliance on archival documents prompts questions related to how he is dealing with the framing in, and selection of, the documents stored in the UK, India and Zanzibar. Bishara’s utilization of the two fatwa collections, the waraqas and the court material stored in the Zanzibar archives similarly raises questions of to which extend these are able to reconstruct the whole story of the legal history of the region.

 “What the longue durée grand narratives depicting Islamic law often tend to forget is that practice and theory are often interlinked, pushing the boundaries of each another.” 
By narrowing temporal and spatial limits, the authors of A Sea of Debt and Margins of the Market show that Muslim merchants and lawmakers were flexible in adapting to the changes that the nineteenth century brought to the Western Indian Ocean. What the longue durée grand narratives depicting Islamic law often tend to forget is that practice and theory are often interlinked, pushing the boundaries of each another. As international commercial practices and finance have changed over time so has the legal devices available in the wider toolbox available to the realm of Islamic law. The debates over riba, or usury, in post-colonial Pakistan is one out of many on-going examples that reflect how different Muslim scholars have sought to reinterpret Islamic jurisprudence in a changing international financial environment. The growth of the Islamic financial industry, especially in England and the United States, and the debates over the different financial devices that are considered ‘sharia compliant’ is similarly beneficial to keep in mind when studying the history of Islamic law and commerce. With their respective manuscripts, Mathew and Bishara show that these debates are not uniquely new –  a crucial lesson for those interested in the history of Islamic law.